Elsevier

Economics Letters

Volume 99, Issue 1, April 2008, Pages 164-167
Economics Letters

A gravity model of immigration

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econlet.2007.06.019Get rights and content

Abstract

This paper develops a gravity model of immigration. Tests of the model using panel data for 16 OECD countries for 1991–2000 confirm the model's high explanatory power, and examples illustrate its usefulness for testing other hypothesized determinants of immigration.

Introduction

Immigration is a controversial issue in many countries, and economists are increasingly called on to explain its causes and consequences. Most economic studies of immigration, such as Friedberg and Hunt (1995), Card (2001), and Borjas (2003), use a standard labor market model in which immigrant workers respond to differences in wages between countries. Many other factors influence immigration, however. This paper offers an adaptable regression model, based on the popular gravity model of international trade, with which to test hypothesized influences on immigration.

The gravity model of trade specifies trade as a positive function of the attractive “mass” of two economies and a negative function of distance between them. Defining TRADEij as total trade between countries i and j, DISTij as the distance between the two countries, and the gravitational “mass” as the product of gross domestic products of countries i and j, the gravity model of trade isTRADEij=f[(GDPiGDPj)/DISTij].

Showing natural logs in lower case, the regression equation is commonly specified astradeij=a0+a1(gdpigdpj)+a2(distij)+uij.

Researchers using the gravity model to explain trade often include variables to control for demographic, geographic, ethnic/linguistic, and economic conditions, as for exampletradeij=a0+a1(gdpigdpj)+a2(popipopj)+a3(distij)+a4BLOCij+a5LANGij+a6CONTij+a7LINKij+uij.

In (3), BLOC, LANG, CONT, and LINK are dummy variables for pairs of countries that share membership in a free trade area, a common language, a contiguous border, and colonial links, respectively, and popi · popj is the log of the product of the populations.

Tinbergen (1962) first used the gravity model to explain international trade patterns, and economists have consistently found it to explain a large proportion of the variation in international trade flows, making the model attractive for testing the marginal influence of other hypothesized variables on international trade. Theoretical justifications for the model have been provided by Linnemann (1966), Anderson (1979), and Deardorff (1998).

Section snippets

A gravity model of immigration

Immigration, like international trade, is driven by the attractive force between immigrant source and destination countries and impeded by the costs of moving from one country to another. The labor market model of immigration suggests that the attractive force between immigrant source and destination countries depends on the difference between labor incomes in the two countries. Population size also matters; ceteris paribus, the more people there are in a source country, the more people are

Econometric methodology for the gravity model

In the regression model (5), each variable is bilateral in that it applies to both countries i and j. However, researchers often want to test the influence on immigration of unilateral variables that reflect characteristics in only the source or destination country. Redding and Venables (2004) and Rose and van Wincoop (2001) show that gravity model estimates are likely to be biased by standard error clustering when some variables in the model apply to only one of the two countries in each

Estimating the gravity model

Table 1 reports the estimates of four gravity regressions using panel data on total legal immigration to each of 16 OECD destination countries from all source countries throughout the world for the ten years 1991–2000. In order to compare the gravity models of trade and immigration, column (1) of Table 1 reports the estimated coefficients for the gravity model of trade from Eq. (3), and column (2) reports the results from estimating the basic gravity model of immigration specified in Eq. (5).

Conclusions

The gravity model of international trade is a useful and popular regression model for testing hypothesized influences on trade flows between pairs of countries. Immigration is likely to respond to gravitational forces and distance in a similar fashion. This paper shows that a gravity model of immigration can be used to test the marginal influence of additional variables on immigration.

References (21)

  • EichengreenB. et al.

    Trade blocs, currency blocs and reorientation of world trade in the 1930s

    Journal of International Economics

    (1995)
  • ReddingS. et al.

    Economic geography and international inequality

    Journal of International Economics

    (2004)
  • ZawodnyM.
  • WangZ.K. et al.

    The trading potential of eastern Europe

    Journal of Economic Integration

    (1992)
  • TinbergenJ.

    Shaping the World Economy

    (1962)
  • RoseA.K. et al.

    National money as a barrier to international trade: the real case for currency union

    American Economic Review

    (2001)
  • RephannT.J. et al.

    Determinants of the spatial mobility of immigrants in Sweden

    Review of Regional Studies

    (2000)
  • MurayamaY.

    Information and immigrants: interprefectual differences of Japanese emigration to the pacific northwest, 1880–1915

    Journal of Economic History

    (1991)
  • LinnemannH.

    An Econometric Study of International Trade flows

    (1966)
  • KaufmannD. et al.

    Aggregating Governance Indicators

    (1999)
There are more references available in the full text version of this article.
1

Tel.: +1 402 202 6997.

View full text