Scientific Reports | Article Open
Spreading of cooperative behaviour across interdependent groups
- Journal name:
- Scientific Reports
- Volume:
- 3,
- Article number:
- 2483
- DOI:
- doi:10.1038/srep02483
- Received
- Accepted
- Published
Recent empirical research has shown that links between groups reinforce individuals within groups to adopt cooperative behaviour. Moreover, links between networks may induce cascading failures, competitive percolation, or contribute to efficient transportation. Here we show that there in fact exists an intermediate fraction of links between groups that is optimal for the evolution of cooperation in the prisoner's dilemma game. We consider individual groups with regular, random, and scale-free topology, and study their different combinations to reveal that an intermediate interdependence optimally facilitates the spreading of cooperative behaviour between groups. Excessive between-group links simply unify the two groups and make them act as one, while too rare between-group links preclude a useful information flow between the two groups. Interestingly, we find that between-group links are more likely to connect two cooperators than in-group links, thus supporting the conclusion that they are of paramount importance.
Subject terms:
At a glance
Figures
-
Figure 1: Schematic presentation of two groups that are connected by means of between-group links. Players in group A originally form a random network, each with degree four, while players in group B form a regular graph, each with degree six. Subsequently, each player in group B severs one of its in-group links (depicted green) with probability p and uses it to form a between-group link (depicted red) with one randomly selected player from group A, the constrain being that no player in either groups is allowed to have more than one between-group link. In the example each group consists of 10 players and p = 0.2.
-
Figure 2: There is an intermediate fraction of between-group links at which the fraction of cooperators is maximal, regardless of the topologies of the two interdependent groups. Panel (a) depicts the overall fraction of cooperators in both groups in dependence on the probability to establish between-group links, as obtained for different topologies of group A (see legend). Panels (b), (c) and (d) depict the fraction of cooperators amongst players with and without between-group links separately (see legend), as obtained when group A has regular, random and scale-free topology, respectively. It can be observed that cooperation is significantly more likely amongst player that do have between-group links. Results were obtained using the temptation to defect b = 1.18.
-
Figure 3: Cooperators are distributed unevenly between the two interdependent groups, depending on the topologies that govern the interactions in each individual group. Panels (a), (b) and (c) depict the fraction of cooperators in groups A and B separately (see legend), as obtained when group A has regular, random and scale-free topology, respectively. If group B is a regular graph, the dilution of links there has a more potent positive impact on cooperation (see68, 69 for related work) than the additional links introduced to group A. Players in group B in general always benefit from an optimal dilution, while players in group A benefit most from the additional links if initially they form a regular graph. If the topology of group A is random [as in panel (b)] or scale-free [as in panel (c)], the new between-group links stemming from players in group B have at most a marginal impact. As in Fig. 2, results were obtained using the temptation to defect b = 1.18.
-
Figure 4: Players that share a between-group link are more likely to both cooperate than players that are connected by means of in-group links. Panels (a) and (b) explain and schematically depict the determination of V, which quantifies the cooperativity of each individual link. If a link connects two cooperators (defectors) V = 1 (V = 0), while cooperator-defector links yield V = 0.5. The example in panel (b) thus yields Vavg = 5.5/12.0 ≈ 0.46 for in-group links, and Vavg = 1.5/3.0 = 0.5 for between-group links. Averaging V separately over all in-group and between-group links under actual conditions yields results presented in panel (c), from where it follows that between-group links are more likely to connect two cooperators than in-group links, especially for low and intermediate values of p. This conclusion is further corroborated by results presented in panel (d), where we show the probability of a player to cooperate in the next round in dependence on the number of its cooperative neighbours. It can be observed that the probability is higher for players that have between-group links than for players without between-group links, especially if the player has only one, two, three of four cooperative neighbours. Results presented in panels (c) and (d) were obtained using random topology for group A and the temptation to defect b = 1.18. For panel (d) we have used p = 0.15.
-
Figure 5: Optimal interdependence between two groups depends on the temptation to defect. Panels (a), (b) and (c) present the colour-encoded fraction of cooperators in both groups in dependence on the probability to establish between-group links p and the temptation to defect b when the topology of group A is regular, random and scale-free, respectively. If the topology of group A is regular, panel (a) reveals that there exists an optimal value of p only for sufficiently large b ≥ 1.15. If the topology of group A is random, there exists an optimal p almost independently of b, although the optimal value of p shifts towards lower values as b increases. If group A has scale-free topology, however, the impact of p is most illusive, since the scale-free topology alone strongly promotes the evolution of cooperation (see22, 23).